home *** CD-ROM | disk | FTP | other *** search
- $Unique_ID{how02118}
- $Pretitle{}
- $Title{History Of Monetary Systems
- Chapter VIII: Anglo-Norman Moneys}
- $Subtitle{}
- $Author{Del Mar, Alexander}
- $Affiliation{}
- $Subject{coins
- silver
- sterlings
- gold
- england
- henry
- norman
- footnote
- money
- moneys}
- $Date{}
- $Log{}
- Title: History Of Monetary Systems
- Book: Chapter VIII: Anglo-Norman Moneys
- Author: Del Mar, Alexander
-
- Chapter VIII: Anglo-Norman Moneys
-
- Chapter Contents
-
- Norman, Anglo-Saxon, early Gothic, Moslem, Byzantine, and other coins
- circulating in England - Difference in the silver value of heretical and
- orthodox gold coins - Scats, sterlings, and pennies - Efforts of the Norman
- princes to escape the monetary supervision of Rome - Receipts and payments
- made in different moneys - Counterfeiting - Barter - Permutation - Fairs -
- Taxes and rents in kind - Bills of exchange - The monetary systems of the
- Norman princes exhibit a strange condition of political affairs.
-
- Anglo-Norman Moneys
-
- During the Norman dynasty the coins in circulation consisted chiefly of
- five classes, namely: Norman, Anglo-Saxon, early Gothic, Byzantine and Moslem.
-
- Norman Coins
-
- These "sterlings," or flat, thin, silver coins of the half-dirhem type,
- containing about 20 grains of silver 0.925 fine, or about 18 1/2 grains of
- fine silver. In modern numismatic works these are always called "pennies." No
- less than twelve thousand of the "pax" sterlings of William I. were discovered
- at Beaworth, in Hampshire, in 1833, besides other large hoards elsewhere.
- Twelve of these sterlings went to the Norman shilling.
-
- It has been assumed by numismatic writers that the sterlings were always
- valued at one penny each; but in face of a contrary practice in France at this
- period, where the sterling was sometimes rated at three half-pence, two pence,
- etc., and of the twopenny sterlings, and threepenny sterlings cited elsewhere
- in the present work, this is by no means certain.
-
- Anglo-Saxon Moneys
-
- The best Anglo-Saxon silver sterlings (scats) were valued at four to the
- Saxon shilling of account, while sixty Saxon shillings were counted to the
- pound of account. These relations were not disturbed by William, who
- continued to employ them in all payments under the Anglo-Saxon laws, or in
- reference to Anglo-Saxon rents and contracts. There were, therefore, two
- moneys of account employed during his reign, namely, the Norman 12 X 20 = 240
- pence to the pound of account, and the Saxon 4 X 60 = 240 pence to the pound
- of account.
-
- Early Gothic Moneys
-
- The ora is valued in Domesday Book at 20 pence, from which it would
- appear that Edward the Confessor's base pennies were meant, or else that
- William's sterlings actually went for twopence each. It has been suggested
- that the ora here meant was either the ora weight of 45 grains (one-eighth of
- the Gothic mark), or else a gold coin of about that weight, say the Moorish
- obolus de Murcia or maravedi, ^1 but in 37 Henry III. (A. D. 1252), the
- maravedi of Moorish Spain was valued at 16 pence ^2 - a fall in value which,
- if it related to a weight of gold bullion, would be difficult to account for,
- but which, if to an actual gold coin, might have been due to its having been
- reduced by abrasion or "rounding," or else to its heretical stamp. But, in
- fact, at the period of Domesday Book, the maravedi was a new coin; therefore
- we regard the first hypothesis as more reasonable. The composite or electrum
- scat had disappeared; the silver scat is mentioned under the name of a penny.
- The brass stycas, so common during the Gothic era, do not appear to have
- remained in circulation during the Norman one, for no mention is made of them
- in extant texts. They were replaced by Roman bronze coins.
-
- [Footnote 1: The maravedi of this period weighed about 43 grains (nearly)
- fine.]
-
- [Footnote 2: Ruding, i, p. 316.]
-
- Moslem Moneys
-
- The Spanish-Arabian dinar (60 to 66 grains fine) and the zecchin (50 to
- 55 grains fine), circulated in England under the misnomers of besant and
- mancus. Norman sterlings of the half-dirhem or sterling type, and containing
- 18 to 20 grains fine silver, had taken the place of the half-dirhems coined in
- Arabian-Spain. Valued in these Norman sterlings, the dinar was worth 34 to 36
- sterlings, and the zecchin 30 to 31 sterlings - a ratio of 9 or 10 for 1. The
- mark of 5 zecchins, afterwards of 5 maravedis, was valued at 160 sterlings.
- The other Moslem coins which circulated in England during this period were the
- gold half-mithcal and a few of the old silver dirhems and half-dirhems.
-
- Byzantine Moneys
-
- These were the gold besants of 65 grains, valued at 40 sterlings - a
- ratio of 12 for 1. ^1 The besant of this period was a thin and slightly
- "dished" gold coin, or "scyphus," with a rayed image on one side. It was the
- direct descendant of the sacred aureus of Augustus and the sacred solidus of
- his successors, the sovereign-pontiffs or emperors of Rome.
-
- [Footnote 1: It results that the ratio for Moslem or heretical gold was 9 or
- 10 silver, and for Byzantine or orthodox gold, 12 silver.]
-
- Other Moneys
-
- Besides these coins the circulating money of England included the silver
- coins of France, Venice and other States. These were rated, by official
- proclamation, at something near their bullion value. Roman bronze coins of
- varied types and designs also circulated among the common people, and,
- according to Sir John Lubbock, they continue to circulate among them, in the
- remoter parts of England, at the present day.
-
- The legal status, history and tale value of bronze or copper coins, and
- an investigation of the authority under which they were struck, during the
- interval between the establishment of Christianity in the provinces and the
- fall of the Sacred Empire in the thirteenth century, is a domain of
- numismatics upon which so little certain light has hitherto been shed, that it
- would perhaps be unsafe to make it a basis for historical induction. There is
- strong reason to believe that the Roman Senate never parted with its authority
- to strike copper, and that during the dark and mediaeval ages the Christian
- provinces were supplied with copper coins struck by moneyers appointed by the
- Senate, first of Rome and afterwards of Constantinople. It is certainly a
- remarkable fact, one well worthy the profoundest attention, that, except when
- at rare intervals they ventured to disregard the authority of the Empire, the
- Christian princes of England struck no copper coins until after the fall of
- Constantinople.
-
- The Anglo-Norman kings coined no gold at all. The coinage of gold ceased
- when Christianity was introduced, and the last gold coins known to have been
- struck in England previous to the reign of Henry III. were the dinars of Offa,
- before his alleged submission to the yoke of the gospel. ^1
-
- [Footnote 1: Two or three heretical exceptions to this rule have been already
- mentioned.]
-
- A good deal of learning has been spent upon that passage in the Black
- Book of the Exchequer (ascribed to William of Tilbury, in the reign of Henry
- II.), which states that a custom was introduced by William I. of requiring
- payments into the treasury to be made ad scalam (by weight). Lowndes treats
- this custom as general, and ascribes it to the universal prevalence of clipped
- and counterfeit coins; but this explanation, in view of the valuations based
- on the Byzantine ratio, and in view of the large hoards of full-weighted
- sterlings which have been found in modern days, is not satisfactory. Madox -
- who if less concise, is more practical - assures us that coins were received
- in the exchequer by deducting sixpence from each twenty shillings, for light
- coins: this was payment ad scalam. When the coins were unusually light they
- were only received as standard bullion: this was payment ad pensum. When
- their purity was in question they were received as crude bullion and sent to
- the refiners and assayers: this was payment by combustion. In brief, this
- means that payments into the exchequer, when made in light or debased coins,
- were, as nearly as possible, subjected to precisely the same regulations that
- they are to-day.
-
- There is no reason for supposing that the phrase "payments into the
- treasury" meant anything more or less than what it literally conveys.
- Notwithstanding the theory of Lowndes, it may be asserted with confidence that
- it did not include other payments, such as payments out of the treasury, nor
- payments between merchants, nor between merchants and nobles. For all these
- classes of payments the king, at times, assumed the right to prescribe
- different sorts of moneys - a right which he invariably relinquished when
- admonished by the sacred college that he was exceeding his powers. In view of
- this tendency of the crown it would be absurd to suppose that when clipped or
- counterfeit coins were received at the treasury by weight, they were re-coined
- or paid out by weight. Nothing of the sort. The revenues came from
- comparatively few sources, whilst payments were made to a vast number of
- people; and payment by weight would have been simply impracticable. On the
- other hand, if the clipped and counterfeit coins received into the treasury
- had been re-coined, it would have taken but a comparatively short time to
- reform the entire currency; but no such reformation appears to have been
- undertaken. The fact is that the crown practically legitimized clipped and
- counterfeit coins, not by receiving them into the treasury ad scalam, but by
- paying them out of the treasury ad numero. Some of the numismatists have
- patriotically paraded one custom, and carefully suppressed the other; but the
- evidences of its practice appear plainly enough in the course of this work to
- satisfy the ordinary demands of reason. The power that scrupled not to
- receive and pay by different weights, would scarcely have hesitated to receive
- and pay with different coins, and it may be confidently believed that this was
- the practice. ^1
-
- [Footnote 1: This practice (elsewhere) is alluded to and condemned in the
- Koran.]
-
- The sterlings assigned by numismatists to William Rufus are slightly
- heavier than those supposed to have been struck by his predecessor, and
- described at the outset of this chapter. The fineness is the same, and the
- two types and designs are so much alike that none but the most expert can
- distinguish them. No other coins are known of the reign of William Rufus.
-
- The sterlings of Henry I., are of about the same weight as those of
- William I. but not quite so fine. These were followed by emissions of debased
- pieces, which it was afterwards pretended were counterfeits. Upon
- instructions - no doubt from the Roman pontificate - a re-coinage was ordered
- in 1108, and the severest sentences were threatened to false coiners. In
- 1123, to lend effect to these threats, the power of Rome was invoked in aid of
- the crown, and the penalties of the canon law were added to those of the
- civil. It is the indifference that was manifested toward these solemn
- injunctions, coupled with circumstances mentioned elsewhere, which leads to
- the suspicion that much of the base coining was done by a class of people who
- knew too much about the crimen majestatis to stand in fear of impeachment. ^2
-
- [Footnote 2: In 1362 the abbot of Missenden was convicted of coining and
- clipping groats and sterlings; in 1369 the canon of Dunmore was accused of
- counterfeiting gold and silver coins; and in 1371 the canon of St. Gilbert de
- Sempingham was charged with secretly conveying coins abroad contrary to law
- (Ruding, ii., pp. 199-208).]
-
- In 1125 the current coins had become so corrupt that a large proportion
- of them would not pass even from hand to hand, and ninety-four accused
- persons, among them several privileged moneyers, underwent mutilation for
- false coining. Some of the numismatic writers have credited Henry I. with
- "abolishing the oppressive tax of moneyage;" but the fact is that he had no
- right even to levy such a tax. Its abolition must be credited, not to Henry,
- but to his suzerain, the pope.
-
- The only coins of Stephen are the sterling pennies of the regular
- Anglo-Norman weight and fineness. There were debased coins struck in
- Stephen's name, but they cannot be traced to the royal mints. Other debased
- coins were struck by Stephen's illegitimate brother, Henry, bishop of
- Winchester; by his illegitimate cousin, Robert, earl of Gloucester; by his two
- sons, Eustace and William, as well as by Roger, earl of Warwick, and numerous
- other prelates and nobles. In 1139 the sum of forty thousand marks, probably
- in debased silver pennies, was captured in the castle of the Devizes, from
- Roger, bishop of Salisbury. In 1181 silver coins, nominally valued at eleven
- thousand pounds, and foreign gold coins, amounting in value to three hundred
- pounds, were found in the treasury of Roger, bishop of York. ^1
-
- [Footnote 1: Dr. Henry, "Hist. Britain," iii., p. 311.]
-
- Ratio
-
- In the reigns of Stephen, Henry II., and John, embracing the period 1140
- to 1216, there occur several entries in the Exchequer Rolls where silver
- bullion appears to have been paid for gold bullion at the ratio of 9 weights
- for 1, and this ratio is supposed by some writers to have been adopted in the
- coin valuations of the first three Norman kings; but such is not the fact -
- the coin ratios were 12 for 1. ^1 In France, also, during the same period, the
- ratio of silver to gold in the official valuations of coins was always 12 for
- 1, and the constant valuation of the mark coin in England at 13s. 4d. affords
- reason to believe that the Roman ratio of 12 to 1 was reflected in the legal
- valuations given to other coins in England.
-
- [Footnote 1: See entry in the Exchequer Rolls 17 John, 1215, where certain
- besants of Constantinople were valued at 3s. 6d. silver each (Madox, ii., p.
- 261). Making allowance for difference of standard between the gold and silver
- coins, and for the probably abraded condition of the former, this evidently
- means a ratio of 12 for 1. At the same time the ratio for bullion was 9 or 10
- for 1. We are not here alluding to the compromise ratios in the coinages of
- the Gothic kings of the heptarchy, shown elsewhere, but to the actual ratios
- for bullion, in 5 Stephen, 2 and 16 Henry II., and 15 and 17 John (Madox, i.,
- p. 277 and ii., 261 u.) The subject has already been alluded to.]
-
- In dealing with this period it should not be forgotten that there were
- but four classes of people who had anything to do with public affairs - the
- imperial authorities, the royal authorities, the nobles, and the
- ecclesiastics. The adulterations of money were committed chiefly by the two
- last-named classes. During the reign of Stephen castles, monasteries and
- fortified retreats sprang up on all sides, some of them supplied with
- implements to fabricate counterfeit money. A large number of these retreats -
- called in official language "robbers' dens" - were destroyed by the first
- Plantagenet king, but no mention is made of counterfeiting, and it was
- probably not common.
-
- "Up to the year 958 the Flemings, Germans and Sarmatians dealt mostly by
- permutation of merchandise." In 959 Baldwin III., earl of Flanders, observing
- that the scarcity of money was an obstruction to the trade with France,
- established markets and fairs, at which merchandise could be permuted without
- money, and declared trade free of export or import dues. ^2 Fairs were held in
- England throughout the entire period of the Roman empire; they were encouraged
- in 1071, tallaged in 1195 (or before); they fell gradually into disuse after
- the discovery of America, and were abolished during the present century as
- "nuisances." The still lingering fairs of Beauclaire, Leipzig, Nijni Novgorod,
- etc., are moribund examples of this now almost extinct but once indispensable
- institution of European industrial life. Nor do we believe with some authors
- that the permutation practiced at fairs was simply barter. The exchanges were
- too numerous and important to be made by barter. It therefore seems likely
- that permutation was a system of clearings. The goods were bought and sold on
- a credit which was to last during the fair. The prices were couched in L. s.
- d. or other moneys, and when the fair closed the clearing was made, thus
- obviating the use of any other money than the final sums needed to effect a
- balance.
-
- [Footnote 2: "Annales Flandriae," year 958, printed at Frankfort 1580, cited
- in Anderson's "Commerce," i., p. 98.]
-
- It is commonly asserted by continental writers that bills of exchange are
- of mediaeval origin, and were first used in England during the reign of Henry
- III. This is entirely erroneous. There are examples of their use in India
- and China backward to remote historical eras; in ancient Babylon; in Pontus
- during the fourth century before our era; and probably also at the same time
- in Greece; in Athens and Rome (tempo Cicero) and probably also for centuries
- before and afterwards; in Constantinople and Carthage about the year A. D.
- 321; at Alexandria, Venice, Amalfi, Sienna, Florence, Barcelona, etc., during
- the Arabian epoch; and in all the cities (including the English "staples") of
- the pagan and Christian Hansas. Bills of exchange were in common use in
- Hamburg in 1188, and it can scarcely be doubted that they were known at the
- same time, and indeed long before, in England. ^1
-
- [Footnote 1: On the early use of bills of exchange consult Lenormant. "La
- Monnaie," i., p. 118; "U. S. Com. Rel.," 1858, p. 311; M. Courcelle Seneuil,
- "Dict. Polit. Econ.," 1853, art., "Lettre de Echange;" Savary; Blanqui; Garni;
- Thompson's "Polit. Econ.;" Del Mar's "History of Money in Ancient States," pp.
- 26 and 106; Eggleston's "English Antiquities," p. 122; Cicero's Letters;
- Anderson's "Hist. Com.," i., p. 171; Eusebius. "Ecc. Hist.," x., c. 6.]
-
- Blanqui says that at least the device of endorsement was unknown during
- the middle ages; but this is also incorrect. An instance of assignment by
- means of written endorsements is given in Madox, i., p. 242, and relates to a
- transaction between two Jews in 18 Edward I., year 1289. It appears on the
- ancient Exchequer Rolls relating to Jewry, and is not mentioned as a novelty.
- Being written upon the dorsal portion of a "membrane," or parchment, it
- afterwards came to be known as an endorsement. ^2
-
- [Footnote 2: The expression "dorse of the membrane" is twice used in Madox,
- i., p. 239.]
-
- Sir Matthew Hale ("Sheriffs' Accounts") proves that during the Norman era
- farms were let variously upon a money rent (numero) or a bullion rent (blanc),
- but that in both cases the actual payments were made in kind. Even the
- payments into the exchequer - which Madox would lead us to infer were always
- made in silver ad scalam, ad pensum, or by combustion - were often made with
- goats and pigs. Lord Liverpool's researches led him to the same conclusion.
- He says (chapter x.) that in the reigns of William I. and William II., and
- during a great part of the reign of Henry I., the king's rents, arising from
- his demesnes (which formed at that time an important part of the royal
- revenue) though reserved in money, were really answered in cattle, corn and
- other provisions, because money was then scarce among the people. ^3 The rents
- of private landholders continued to be paid in kind down to a still later
- period. The best evidence with respect to this matter is given by the writer
- of the Black Book, or Liber Niger Scaccarii, cited elsewhere, who avers that
- he had conversed with men who saw the rents brought in kind to the king's
- court.
-
- [Footnote 3: However, they were commuted for money by Henry I. (And, "Com."
- i., p. 248-55) This was probably after his various coinages had rendered money
- sufficiently plentiful.]
-
- Such are the monetary monuments, and such were the monetary systems, of
- the Anglo-Norman kings. That attempts were made to harmonize the diverse
- materials of which they were composed - Roman, early Gothic, Moslem,
- Anglo-Saxon, Carlovingian and Byzantine - is proved by the intervaluations of
- Domesday Book, and the gradual suppression and disappearance of some of these
- materials, chiefly the early Gothic and Moslem; but it is equally evident that
- the attempt was only partially successful, and that there yet remained - as,
- for example, in the mark and pound - an incongruous medley of pagan and
- Christian denominations, and in the divided authority to coin - for example -
- to the Basileus gold, and to the kings, nobles and prelates silver (upon
- conditions) - another medley, which faithfully reflected the general confusion
- of a period whose history was one of personal wars, personal combats and
- personal displays of heroism, chivalry or religious devotion. Coeur de Lion is
- its false ideal; Froissart was its true historian; and all attempts to deduce
- from such materials an independent national existence or policy for France,
- England, Germany or Spain during this early period have been both unsuccessful
- and misleading.
-
-